“The tradition of all dead generations weighs like a nightmare
on the brains of the living,” Marx remarked in The Eighteenth Brumaire, and although we may all make our own
futures, we do not make them just as we please. For such reasons, we social
scientists tend to look to the past to explain the present, to show the particular historical trajectory that led things
to be the way the are. All the same, privileging the past can allow us to forget that
people in the present are not trying to (just) recreate yesterday, but have an
eye toward tomorrow and next year and the lives of their children and
grandchildren.
Unlike Marx’s vivid prose, today the dismal science (qua
science) often forgets about the human passions behind their numbers. In the
sterile statistical world of GDP and interest rates, it is easy to loose sight
of the hopes and dreams, the aspirations and fears—what Keynes termed our
“animal spirits”—and the individual lives behind all economic transactions.
In a remarkable new volume, Jens Beckert (Imagined Futures: Fictional Expectations and
Capitalist Dynamics) moves us toward conceptually linking the passions and
animal spirits of lived experience with a macro-understanding of the workings
of capitalism. He does this by focusing on the future, and the fictive
qualities of imagining the future that underwrite capitalist dynamics.
In this meticulously researched and engagingly written
volume, Beckert uncovers the role of imagined futures as a fundamental driver
of capitalism. It is the sort of observation that makes complete sense when you
hear it, but that has gone largely unremarked upon until now. He shows that the
future orientation of capitalism is based on competition and credit,
fundamental elements at the very core of the financial system. (I would add,
also the construction of desires, especially in late capitalist formations.)
The financial system is built on credit, and demands continual expansion and
continual returns. We are all in bad shape if growth stops, as our retirement
and much of our insurance depends on markets continuing to expand—not to
mention our subjective hopes and dreams.
Beckert makes the provocative point that a lot of what we
consider to be risk (and thus manageable, knowable, predictable) is actually
uncertainty. We make up stories about the future, and convince ourselves and
others that these are more or less likely (in a statistically predictable
manner). For example, investment in innovation requires collectively deciding
to believe in a fictional future. And, as with innovation, imaginaries can
create structures that make real the fictional expectations (186).
In the realm of consumption, Beckert identifies two key
types of symbolic value: (1) positional and (2) imaginative. Positional values
(first observed by Veblen) derive from the scarcity of a good and how many
others have it; rather than absolute material utility, the positional value of
a good is only given by its relation to other goods. With imaginative value, “a
good functions as a link between subject and her desired but intangible ideals”
(195). Imaginative value gets at what it means to the person herself, more than
just positional/status importance. With imaginative value, a good embodies
something transcendent.
Berkert’s new book is exhilarating, opening up new
possibilities for thinking about (and acting on) the market. It gives us a way
to insert the social and the cultural back into the fundamental mechanics of
capitalism, from wince it has long been banished.
Jens Beckert’s Imagined
Futures: Fictional Expectations and Capitalist Dynamics. 2016, Harvard U Press.
No comments:
Post a Comment